CONSTRAINTS IMPOSED ON MANAGERIAL DISCRETION IN PUBLIC CORPORATIONS
- Compiled and Written by Judith Duru, Oladoke Olusegun & Sele Michael (Msc Class, May 2017)
INTRODUCTION
We present
constraints to managerial discretion in public corporations analysing the
conflicts that exist between the managers and shareholders and the relationship
between managerial discretion and public corporation performance. This is
carefully done as we break down what managerial discretion is all about as well
as the nature of public corporation so that we can create a fit in. We also
reflect on how deregulation affects managerial discretion and discuss the
mechanics used to control agency problems, that is, the composition of the
board of directions.
According to
Obaji (2004), Constraints on managerial discretion are the possible conflicts
of interest between stakeholders and managers. Managerial discretion is the
extent to which managers fail to experience discipline on their behaviours from
internal corporate governance e.g. ownership structure and board composition
and external control mechanism e.g. product market composition, credit market,
market for corporate control and managerial market.
Audretsch
and Lehmann (2002), consider that analyzing the relationship between managers
and shareholders requires different perspectives in firms belonging to the
sector of “new” economy and in firms belonging to more traditional industry.
Rajan and Zingales (2000), argue that “new economy” firms need new corporate
governance mechanisms to stimulate the innovation potential of human capital.
Managerial discretion is an important element of corporate governance
mechanism. Since intellectual capital becomes the most important strategic
resource for high-tech firms, should high-tech firms arrange different
managerial discretion from traditional enterprise.
WHAT
IS MANAGERIAL DISCRETION
According
to Oliver E. Williamson, he hypothesized (1964) that profit
maximization would not be the objective of the managers of a joint stock
organization. This theory, like other managerial theories of the firm, assumes
that utility maximization is a manager’s sole objective. However it is only in
a corporate form of business organization that a self-interest seeking manager
can maximize his/her own utility, since there exists a separation of ownership
and control. The managers can use their ‘discretion’ to frame and execute
policies which would maximize their own utilities rather than maximizing the
shareholders’ utilities. This is essentially the principal-agent problem. This could
however threaten their job security, if a minimum level of profit is not
attained by the firm to distribute among the shareholders.
The
basic assumptions of the model are:
- Imperfect competition in the markets.
- Divorce of ownership and management.
- A minimum profit constraint exists for the firms to be able to pay dividends to their share holders.
Managerial
discretion has been an important concept in the economics and management
literatures, from very different perspectives. In economics, managerial
discretion refers to the freedom managers have to pursue their own objectives
(pay, power, status and prestige) rather than shareholder interests: high
discretion means managers are able to pursue personal objectives without being
caught or punished (Williamson, 1963). In the management literature by contrast
managerial discretion refers to the choice of actions available to managers in
the pursuit of organizational goals: high discretion means managers have low
environmental and organizational constraints on their choice of actions, (Hambrick
and Finkelstein,1987).
Shen
and Cho (2005) usefully integrated both points of view into a single framework
which differentiates two aspects of managerial discretion: latitude of
objectives and latitude of actions. Latitude of objectives refers to a
manager’s freedom to pursue their own objectives rather than those of other
stakeholders. Latitude of actions, on the other hand, refers to differing
ranges of actions available for managers to pursue organizational objectives.
MEANING OF PUBLIC CORPORATION
A
public corporation is that form of public enterprise which is created as an
autonomous unit, by a special Act of the Parliament or the State Legislature.
Since
a public corporation is created by a Statute; it is also known as a statutory
corporation.
The
Statute defines the objectives, powers and functions of the public corporation.
Power Holding Company of Nigeria (PHCN), Nigeria Ports Authority (NPA), Bank of
Industry (BOI), Nigeria National Petroleum Corporation (NNPC) and Federal Radio
Corporation of Nigeria (FRCN) etc. are some examples of public corporations, in
Nigeria.
Features
of Public Corporation:
Following
are the salient features of a public corporation:
1.
Special
Statute: A public
corporation is created by a special Act of the Parliament or the State
Legislature. The Act defines its powers, objectives, functions and relations
with the ministry and the Parliament (or State Legislature).
2.
Separate
Legal Entity: A
public corporation is a separate legal entity with perpetual succession and
common seal. It has an existence, independent of the Government. It can own
properly; can make contracts and file suits, in its own name.
3.
Capital
provided by the Government:
The capital of a public corporation is provided by the Government or by
agencies controlled by the government. However, many public corporations have
also begun to raise money from the capital market.
4.
Financial
Autonomy: A public
corporation enjoys financial autonomy. It prepares its own budget; and has
authority to retain and utilize its earnings for its business.
5.
Management
by Board of Directors: Its
management is vested in a Board of Directors, appointed or nominated by the
Government. But there is no Governmental interference in the day-to-day working
of the corporation.
6.
Own
Staff: A publication
corporation has its own staff; whose appointment, remuneration and service
conditions are decided by the corporation itself.
7.
Service
Motive: The main
objective of a public corporation is service-motive; though it is expected to
the self-supporting and earn reasonable profits.
8.
Public
Accountability: A
public corporation has to submit its annual report on its work. Its accounts
are audited by the Comptroller and Auditor General of Nigeria. Annual report
and audited accounts of a public corporation are presented to the Parliament or
State Legislatures.
MANAGERIAL DISCRETION IN PUBLIC CORPORATIONS
Managerial
discretion, which refers to executives’ ability to affect important
organizational outcomes, is a function of the task environment the internal
organization, and managerial characteristics. Managerial discretion occurs in
public corporations when owners of organization or governments enjoy exclusive
control rights over managers. When there exist non-owner control over managers,
managerial discretion may produce a favourable effect on corporate performance,
if the objective functions of managers is relatively more in line with profit
maximization rather than to the non-owner controlling party.
Public
corporation is not suitable in industries where long-term growth is slow, where
internally-generated funds outstrip the opportunities to invest them profitably
or where downsizing is the most productive long-term strategy. The public
corporation is a social invention of vast historical importance. Its genius is
rooted in its capacity to spread financial risk over the diversified portfolio
of millions of individuals and institutions and to allow investors customize
risk to their unique circumstances. By diversifying risks that would otherwise
be borne by owner-entrepreneurs and by facilitating the creation of a liquid
market for exchanging risks, the public corporation lowers the cost of capital.
CONSTRAINTS
ON MANAGERIAL DISCRETION
The degree of discretion that senior
executive managers have in setting objectives is limited by both external
and internal constraints. External constraints arise from the active market in
company shares while internal constraints arise from the role of nonexecutive
board members and stakeholders, trying to align the managers’ and
the owners’ interests by the rules shaping corporate governance.
External
constraints
There are five sources of external
constraint on managerial behaviour in any system of corporate control.
Those who potentially hold this power are:
1. Holders of large blocks of shares who
use or threaten to use their voting power to change management or their policies
if they become dissatisfied.
2. Acquirers of blocks of shares sold by
existing shareholders unhappy with the performance of management.
3. Bidders in the takeover process who
promise to buy all the voting shares of the enterprise.
4. Debtors/Investors, particularly in
times of financial distress, who act to protect their interests in the company.
5. External regulators and auditors.
In
outsider systems, external control is exercised mainly through the workings of
the stock market rather than voting.
The
influence of the workings of the stock market on managerial discretion assumes
that a fall in the share price will make management more vulnerable to
shareholder activism either in selling shares or in voting at shareholder
meetings.
Other external constraints on managerial
behaviour are the need to comply with company law, independent auditing of
accounts and the lodging of company accounts with the regulators.
Internal Constraints
The
organizational structure of the company, there are groups who may be able to
influence management to change policies.
The
first of these are the non-executive directors, who are appointed to the boards
of UK companies to oversee the behaviour of the executive directors. However,
they are normally appointed by the executive managers and, therefore, may not
be independent in their actions or effective in constraining executive
directors. They are often few in number and can be outvoted by executive
directors. One of the objectives of corporate governance reform in the UK is to
make non-executives more effective. In the German system the supervisory board
plays this role by influencing the management board, but its membership is more
wide-ranging.
The
second of these groups are the owners or shareholders, who can exercise their authority
at meetings of the company or informally with management. Directors are elected
at the annual general meeting of the company. Dissatisfied shareholders can
vote against the re-election of existing executive directors or seek to get
nominees elected. They can also vote against resolutions proposed by the
executive of the company, such as those relating to executive remuneration. In
the past this has rarely happened as shareholders have been passive rather than
active in company affairs and sell under-performing shares. However, in the UK
institutional shareholders have become more active in organizing coalitions to
either influence management behind the scenes or forcing votes at annual
general meetings.
A
third group that can influence executive managers are the stakeholders within
the company. These include employees of the firm as well as customers,
suppliers, lenders and the local community. They may do this by expressing
their criticisms concerns either directly to the executives or indirectly by
informing shareholders, the media and outside experts or commentators.
Investment banks and stockbrokers offer advice to shareholders on the potential
future earnings of the company, and such comments may help to influence
attitudes toward incumbent managers.
THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN MANAGERIAL
DISCRETION, PUBLIC CORPORATION PERFORMANCE AND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE
The
relationship between managerial discretion and public corporation is assumed
that government own exclusive rights to control and monitor the managers. More
studies indicate that the absence of external control Mechanism, an increase in
managerial discretion implies a decrease in control by the owners; the result
of which is more operating leeway, for undesirable behaviour on the part of the
managers. As a result, a negative relationship between managerial discretion
and a public corporation performance is expected.
Corporate governance is the system of rules,
practices and processes by which a company is directed and controlled.
Corporate governance essentially involves balancing the interests of a
company's many stakeholders,
such as shareholders, management, customers, suppliers, financiers, government
and the community. Since corporate governance also provides the framework for
attaining a company's objectives, it encompasses practically every sphere of
management, from action plans and internal controls to performance measurement and corporate disclosure.
The
ownership and control of firms are pronounced and vary dramatically across organizations.
Therefore, one of the questions that arise when considering whether or not
corporate governance affects performance includes whether or not
owner-controlled firms are more profitable than manager-controlled firms? A
priority, it is not clear whether or not concentrated ownership and control
will improve performance. On the one hand, concentrated ownership by providing
better monitoring incentives should lead to better performance. On the other
hand, it might also lead to the extraction of private benefits by controlling block-holders (A block-holder is the owner of a large amount of a
company's shares and/or bonds, or block) at
the expense of minority shareholders. These issues are central to the debate
surrounding corporate governance practices, particularly since concentrated
holdings are the primary
means of control. A common feature of large public corporations is the
separation of ownership and control between the principal and the agent (Fama
and Jensen, 1983).
Therefore, whether or not the agency problem arising
from the separation of ownership and control is a serious one and does
concentrated ownership effectively overcome these problems in public
corporation is present. The principle-agent model suggests that managers are
less likely to engage in strictly profit maximizing behaviour in the absence of
strict monitoring by shareholders. Therefore, if owner-controlled firms are
more profitable than manager-controlled firms, it would seem that insider
systems have an advantage in that they provide better monitoring which leads to
better performance. The vast majority of empirical studies, turns out, do to
favour the beneficial effects of enhanced monitoring as a result of higher
ownership concentration.
MANAGER/SHAREHOLDERS
CONFLICT
A central weakness and source of waste in the large public corporation
is the conflict between shareholders and managers over the pay-out of free cash
flow that is, cash flow in excess of that required to fund all investment
projects with positive net present values when discounted at the relevant post
of capital. For a company to operate efficiently and maximize value, free cash
flow must be distributed to shareholders rather than retained. But this happens
infrequently, as senior managers have few mechanisms to compel
distribution.
Managers-stockholders; conflicts are introduced by considering the fact
that, in addition to his fixed wage, the manager derives utility form both
retaining control and investing new project:
A common determinant of capital structure arises from manager-shareholders’
conflicts. Managers and shareholders have different objectives. In particular,
managers tend to value investment more than shareholders do. Graham (2000)
holds that debt financing can increase a firm’s value by reducing the costs
associated with the conflict.
Other key points to why Manager/Shareholder conflict abounds in Public
corporations are;
1. The
agency view of the corporation
suggests that the decision rights of the corporation should be entrusted to a
manager to act in shareholders' interest.
Agency costs mainly occur when ownership is separated, or when managers have
objectives other than shareholder value maximization.
2. Typically,
the CEO and other top executives are responsible for making decisions about
high-level policy and strategy.
Shareholders, on the other hand, are individuals or institutions that legally
own shares of corporation stock.
Shareholders typically concede control rights to managers.
3. There
are various conflicts of interest that can impact manager's decisions to act
in shareholders' interests. Management may, for example, buy other companies to
expand power. Venturing onto fraud, they may even manipulate financial figures
to optimize bonuses and stock-price-related options.
4. Contemporary
discussions of corporate governance argue that corporations should respect the rights of
shareholders and help shareholders to exercise those rights. Disclosure and transparency are
intimately intertwined with these goals.
THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE BOARD OF DIRECTORS AND THE MANAGEMENT IN MANAGERIAL DISCRETION
The relationship between the board of
directors and the management cannot be described as just being that of a
relationship between an employee and his or her manager. Though the board
oversees the decisions taken by the management and ratifies them along with
acting as the final arbiters of the strategic direction and focus that the
company is heading into, the relationship goes beyond that. For instance, the
board of directors is responsible for the actions of the management and hence
not only does the board need to monitor the management, the management needs to
take the board into confidence about its decisions. Hence, the relationship can
be described as being symbiotic with each with each serving in an ecosystem
called the organization. The point here is that neither the management nor the
board can exist without each other and hence both need each other to survive
and flourish.
Another aspect to the relationship
between the board and the management is that more often than not, there is a
significant representation of the management in the board. This means that the
other board members have to study the decisions taken by these members
carefully so that there are no agency problems, conflicts of interest and
asymmetries of information.
Only when the board and the management
coexist together in a harmonious manner can there be true progress for the
organization. For this to happen, there must be a provision for having
independent directors and those directors that are not affiliated to the
management. The point here is that unless there is objectivity and separation
of the directors belonging to the management and those from outside can there
is a semblance of avoidance of conflict of interest.
The third aspect of the relationship
between the board and the management is the role played by institutional
investors or directors from large equity houses and mutual fund companies.
These directors bring to the table rich and varied expertise and experience in
running companies and hence their input is crucial to the working of the
company. It is for this reason that many regulators insist on having a certain
percentage of the board as independent directors and another percentage from
institutional shareholders. The reason for this is the fact that unless there
is a process of due diligence and oversight over the actions of the management,
the management can take unilateral decisions that are not always in the best interests
of the company.
CONCLUSION
Managerial discretion, which refers to executives’
ability to affect important organizational outcomes, is a function of the task
environment the internal organization, and managerial characteristics.
A public
business corporation establishes a compensation committee consisting of outside
directors that sets the salaries, incentive bonuses, and other forms of
compensation of the top-level executives of the organization. An outside
director is one who has no management position in the business and who,
therefore, should be more objective and should not be beholden to the chief
executive of the business.
This is good
in theory, but it doesn’t work out that well in practice — mainly because the
top-level executive of a large public business typically has the dominant voice
in selecting the persons to serve on its board of directors. Being a director
of a large public corporation is a prestigious position, to say nothing of the
annual fees that are substantial at most corporations
Finally, the relationship between the board and management is somewhat strained
whenever the company is not doing well. This happens because the board has a
top view of the organization and the management has a deeper insight.
Hence, to be fair to the management, they are the ones who have to run the
organization and so they cannot be constrained by what the board dictates
sitting on its perch. This is the classic problem that many companies face
especially when they are not doing well and the remedy for this is to take the
board into confidence about the complexities of the day to day operations and
apprise them of the nuances and subtleties of running the organization.
References:
1. International Management Journal, Kenny Crossan, The Theory of the
Firm and Alternative Theories of Firm Behaviour: A Critique. International
Journal of Applied Institutional Governance Volume 1 Issue 1; ISSN 1747-6259.
2.
D.
D. Tewari, Katar Singh (2003). Principles of Microeconomics. New Age
International Publishers. pp. 92. ISBN 81-224-1017-0.
4.
Geetika,
Piyali Ghosh, Purba Roy Choudhury (2009). Managerial Economics. The McGraw-Hill
Companies. pp. 50. ISBN 978-0-07-026365-9.
5.
Mukund
Mahajan (2008). Managerial Economics, third edition. Nirali Prakashan. pp.
10.15.
6.
HAMBRICK,
D. C. & FINKELSTEIN, S. 1987. Managerial discretion: a bridge between polar
views of organizational outcomes. Research in Organizational Behavior,9, 369.
9.
Baumol,
W. J. (19590, business behaviour, value and growth, New York:
Macmillan.
10. Baysinger, B, D. and Butter, H.
(1985), “corporate governance and board of directors’ performance: effect of
changes in board composition”.
11. Journal of law, economics, and
organisation”, vol. 1, pp. 101-120.
12. Dixit, A. (1997) “Power of Incentives
in Private Versus Public Organisations.”
13. American Economic Review, vol. 74,
No. 4, pp.650-656.Dec.
14. Fama, E. F. (1980) “Agency Problems
And The Theory Of The Firm” Journal of Political Economics, vol. 88, No. 2,
pp288-296, April.
15. Fama, E.F. and Jenson M. C. (1983),
“Separation of Ownership and Control, Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 26,
No. 1, pp301-326, June.
16. Finkelstein, E. and Boyd, B. (1998),
“How Much Does CEO Matter? The Role of Managerial Discretion in Setting of CEO
Compensation” Academy of Management Journal, vol. 41, pp. 179-188.
17. Corporate Governance: The
international Journal of Business Society, 2001. Vol 3. ISSN: 1412 0701
18. Grucia. T. S. and Nath, D. (1994),
“Regulatory Change, Constraints on Adaptation and Organisational Failure: An
Empirical Analysis of Acute Care Hospital”, Strategic Management Journal, vol.
15, pp. 245-360.
19. Hill, C. W. L. (2001), International
Business, Competing in the Global Marketplace: Postscript 2001, New York: Irwin
McGraw Hill.
20. Jones, T. M. and Goldberg, L.
(1982), “Governing the Large Corporation: More Argument for Public Directors”,
Academy of Management Review, vol. 7, pp.603- Williamson, E. O. (1984),
Corporate Governance, Yale Law Journal, vol.93, pp197-230.
21. Williamson, O. (1963), “Managerial
Discretion and Business Behaviour”. American Economic Review, vol. 53, No. 5,
pp. 103-108, Dec.
The Compilation of this work was carried out by Masters of Sciences student of University of Abuja, Business Administration (16/17) department as part of their presentation work in a Comparative Management course.
The Compilation of this work was carried out by Masters of Sciences student of University of Abuja, Business Administration (16/17) department as part of their presentation work in a Comparative Management course.
Comments
Post a Comment